Regional Regulators Conference
9 January 1995 |   By : Dato' Dr. Mohd. Munir Abdul Majid, Chairman, Securities Commission, Malaysia

It is my privilege to welcome you to Malaysia, especially to those here for the first time. The Securities Commission, Malaysia takes pleasure in hosting this Regional Regulators Workshop, the first of its kind to be held in this region. The purpose of this workshop is to promote understanding of as well as sharing of knowledge and experience on regulation and development of capital markets. The week's programme would take us through a wide range of topics covering regulatory systems, policy framework for capital market development, market infrastructure, clearing and settlement issues, enforcement programmes, privatisation of state owned enterprises and other relevant topics. We have a gathering of participants from about twenty countries, and speakers who have experience as regulators in the developed and emerging markets, plus practioners from across the region. A gathering of individuals from such varied professional, cultural and regulatory background provides an excellent forum for learning and discussion.

In this morning's address I would like to discuss the developmental and disciplinary role of regulators in emerging markets. The most important starting point in this discussion is a reminder on the basic social purpose and objective for which financial markets exist, which is to facilitate capital formation to fund real economic development. This reminder is important because the processes and activities can become so esoteric and removed from common understanding, that the participants and regulators in those markets may get so caught up in their own world that they may forget the real one. The securities market therefore exists to fulfil certain basic functions regardless of trading volume, the variety of instruments and market infrastructure, or the degree of automation in the market making process although, I wish to emphasise, I'm not saying these are not important considerations. Indeed they are to ensure success of the capital formation process. And, on the other side, just as important for that same reason, are prudential safeguards essential to minimise fraud, manipulation and systemic risks inherent in capital marktets. ' The markets must function and grow, and they must be protected and stable. The developmental and disciplinary roles are, therefore, intertwined. One cannot function without the other, just as a house however magnificent will soon collapse if built on weak foundations. With physical constructions you can build all over again but with markets the confidence that can be so quickly lost needs a long time to be recovered.

There is thus no contradiction between the developmental and disciplinary roles regulators have to discharge. They are indeed complementary, although the emphasis on one as against the other will vary over time and in various instances. In the end, however, there must be a balance between the two, and this is the difficult task that confronts all regulators.

Allow me next to explore some of the regulatory functions which necessarily have both developmental and disciplinary components.

Firstly, the regulatory framework must define the key features of the financial system and the role of market institutions such as exchanges, clearing houses and depository institutions within that system. At the macro level, the boundaries of regulation must be clear and well defined; in many countries the banking and securities markets are regulated under separate government authorities. The number and types of institutions are not stagnant. As markets develop, regulators will be faced with the dynamic task of setting up new institutions for new activities or to provide support services to the industry. Futures exchanges will be established for an orderly development for the derivatives markets. Clearing and settlement organisations and depository institutions must exist to provide an effective and stable payments system, improve the ability of securities firms to manage their risks exposures, reduce the accumulation of significant counterparty risks and minimise the movement of scrip handling. The success of this developmental role is of primary importance to minimise systemic risk in the financial market and to maintain public confidence as trading volume increases and new instruments are introduced.

The second function is to improve the transparency and efficiency of the market. Regulators must strive to achieve

  • Quality reporting by public listed companies
  • Timely disclosure of price sensitive information to the investing public
  • An efficient and fair price matching mechanism for trading of securities

The disclosure requirements vary between countries. For example, in some countries, the regulatory philosophy on disclosure for issue of securities gives the disciplinary role back to the market participants, encouraging issuers and market intermediaries to provide timely and complete disclosures. The regulators will not seek to evaluate the merits of the issuer, the disclosures required are detailed and complete leaving the investors to decide on the merits of the investment. This philosophy is backed by strong sanctions for improper disclosures and the high probability that violators will be caught and penalised. Market participants, in these jurisdictions, therefore have an incentive to avoid making damaging disclosures in maintaining their own integrity.

The other disclosure model, commonly known as 'merit regulation' requires qualitative and judgemental review by the regulators, involving a detailed scrutiny of the prospectus, the pricing of the issue and other disclosure documents. This system has its merits in protecting investors, especially the retail investors who may not be accustomed to assessing the risks in an investment by perusing a prospectus document. One of the drawbacks of this system is the Iengthy approval period in the merit review process. In deciding the model to adopt regulators must consider the adequacy of sanction powers it has over the violaters, and the level of responsibility by the professionals, issuers, directors and investment banker must be well understood. In emerging markets where public confidence is paramour a faded public listed company could lead to public outcry by retail investors and politicians notwithstanding that full disclosure was made in the prospectus.

During the past 25 years or so, volumes of literature has been churned out that support the hypothesis that financial markets are, in one degree or another, efficient. How efficient is a matter of debate amongst academics and practioners even today. Eugene Fama was amongst the pioneers in finance theory that expounded on the three forms of market efficiency, the weak, semi strong and strong form. In its most basic form, the efficient market hypothesis states that the current price of securities incorporates all relevant and available information. New price sensitive information that comes into the market will be random and is quickly reflected in the stock price. Because the new information is random one cannot predict future price movements from past trends. The behaviour of stock prices therefore resembles a random walk as prices respond to each new random event.

Each of the three levels of market efficiency has been subjected to widespread statistical testing over the years. Empirical evidence suggest that developed capital markets are not efficient in the theoretical sense, though not fully conclusively. Two common anomalies found in the United States are that small cap stocks tend to outperform the S&P 500, and the January effect, a successful timing strategy of buying selective stocks in December and selling for a profit in January. However there are other evidence that support the view that markets are efficient. Professional managers as a group have failed to outperform the markets over a long period of time implying that you cannot beat an efficient market.

As regulators we are not to contend with these or take a position with regard to those on going debates. Our interest is to establish rules for a transparent and efficient market. These rules will require companies to disclose information about their assets and earnings, changes in directors shareholdings and other significant price sensitive information on a timely basis. These information must then be efficiently disseminated to the investing public to allow investors to make timely decisions on their investments.

The third type of regulatory activity is in the areas of enforcement, investigation and prosecution,-a role which quickly comes to mind when people think of " regulation. Securities markets are characterised by systemic risks, the risk that could infect the entire financial system resulting from the collapse of a single institution or a sector of the market. Two examples in the eighties come to mind. The Pan Electric crisis in Malaysia and Singapore in the early eighties and the global effect of Wall Street's October 87 stock market crash. At times, though, the markets have been resilient to the insolvency of a single, large institution. For example, when Drexel, Bumham and Lambert announced on 13th February, 1990, that it was filing for Chapter 11 bankruptcy, the news set off declines in stock and bond prices on Wall Street. Prices of junk bonds subsequently collapsed. There were fears of the spiral effects of counterparty defaults risk amongst Wall Street's investment banks, and many lost money, but the market survived. And, similarly the banking community in Massachussets survived the insolvency of Bank of New England in 1991, largely helped by the national deposits insurance schema.

Systemic risks in the above instances are the results of improper conduct by an individual, Or a group of individuals. The disciplinary role of the regulator must be effective to restrain improper market conduct such as insider trading, market manipulation, improper corporate disclosure or front running. These are issues concerning ethics, and promoting good ethics within the industry becomes a key developmental role.

Good ethics would include honesty, courage, compassion and restraint. We look for integrity as a combination of many of these values. In many ways personal values define a person more than other characteristics such as colour, sex and other physical attributes. Like physical characteristics, ethics are ultimately visible. Unlike physical characteristics, ethics involves conscious choices by individuals. These choices have consequences, sometimes irreversible. Mistakes of character are different from mistakes made resulting in poor business judgement, they determine a whole career. In short ethical lapses ruin careers, tarnish reputations, and diminish public confidence in securities markets Good ethics, however, is good business for those who wish to be around for the long term. And Good ethics are essential for the long term health of the market. When investors perceive that markets are fair and efficient they will give a vote of confidence and not take their money out at the first sign of a bear market.

Let me now say a few words about IOSCO, the International Organisation of Securities Commissions, since many here are members of this organisation. IOSCO provides a major international forum for mutual consultation and collaboration on regulatory issues relevant to the securities business, including the growing cross border business. The organisation's broad aim is to is to help one another develop a safe and sound market system for investor protection and confidence. The member agencies of IOSCO have formalised their objectives as follows:

  • Cooperate to improve the regulation of domestic and international markets
  • Exchange information on their experiences, and adopt best practices in order to promote the development of national markets
  • To provide mutual assistance to ensure the integrity of the markets by a rigorous application of standards and by effective enforcement against offences.

IOSCO has further set up various committees and working groups to spearhead issues of primary concern. The IOSCO Development Committee now called the Emerging Markets Committee was established to promote the exchange of pertinent information and implementation of common standards. This involves dealing with such matters as clearing and settlements, custodial services, derivatives and disclosures. The Working Group on Disclosure, for example, aims to create a set of minimum disclosure standards for investor protection in member countries.

Let me end by thanking Terry Chuppe of Emerging Markets Institute for his assistance in arranging this event and the other main speakers, Robert Rozen and Lee Pickard from the States, and Lai Hung Kee from Hong Kong. And also the various speakers who have come from far and near to speak and to lead in discussions. And to the participants, I trust you will find this workshop beneficial and have a pleasant stay at this beautiful place.
SC AFFILIATES
RELATED SITES
about the SC
The Securities Commission Malaysia (SC) was established on 1 March 1993 under the Securities Commission Act 1993 (SCA). We are a self-funded statutory body entrusted with the responsibility to regulate and develop the Malaysian capital market.

General Line: +603-6204 8000
General Email: [email protected]
© Copyright Securities Commission Malaysia.  Contact Us   |    Disclaimer   |   The site is best viewed using Microsoft Edge and Google Chrome with minimum resolution of 1280x1024
Ooops!
Generic Popup